10. Toward Cliodynamics: an Analytical, Predictive Science of History

History, Big History, & Metahistory
DOI: 10.37911/9781947864023.10

10. Toward Cliodynamics: an Analytical, Predictive Science of History

Author: Peter Turchin, University of Connecticut 

 

Excerpt

This article responds to those who think that a science of history is in principle impossible. First, I tackle the issue of prediction and point out that it is not limited to forecasting the future. Scientific prediction is also (and much more usefully) employed in empirical tests of scientific theories. Next, I switch from conceptual to empirical issues, and review evidence for general empirical regularities. I also discuss some recent examples of using scientific prediction in testing theories about historical dynamics. I conclude by pointing out that we now have the right quantitative tools and, even more important, a growing corpus of historical data for testing theories. An analytical, predictive history, or cliodynamics, is eminently possible.

Introduction

Philosophers have long debated whether history can be a science in the same sense that physics and biology are sciences. At the heart of the debate are two opposing views of history. Nineteenth century thinkers, such as Leo Tolstoy and Carl von Clausewitz (see Gaddis, this volume, Chapter 3), believed that historical process was governed by some kind of general laws. Many French and English historians of the nineteenth century viewed history as a science [42]. Twentieth-century historians such as Toynbee [31] proposed grand schemes to account for the rise, the flowering, and the decline of civilizations. A less ambitious (but in the long run more influential) effort by McNeill [17] is another example of an attempt to discern patterns in history. 

During the second half of the twentieth century, however, the general opinion among philosophers and historians swung against the possibility of scientific history. For example, Karl Popper [18] argued that there is a qualitative difference between history and natural sciences. Historical processes are too complex and different in nature from physical or biological processes. Most tellingly, people have free will, while atoms do not. 

Among the historians, research paradigms that modeled themselves on natural sciences were still popular in the 1960s and 1970s [43]. Perhaps the most influential of such research programs was the French Annales school of history. During these decades the new economic history, or cliometrics, briefly flowered in the United States [44]. However, in the 1980s historians repudiated these approaches. As one reviewer of an early version of this article wrote, “cliometrics went under by the early 1990s; our own quantitative historian was denied tenure in approximately 1996 (by that point, no one really cared about the subject or its application in history).” Instead history experienced its “linguistic turn” or “cultural turn” [44, 45].

References

[1] Barfield, T. J. The Perilous Frontier: Nomadic Empires and China. Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1989.

[2] Beatty, J. “Historical Determinism, Evolution and Totalitarianism in the Works of Hannah Arendt and Karl Popper.” In Thinking about Evolution: Historical, Philosophical and Political Perspectives, edited by R. Singh, C. Krimbas, D. Paul, and J. Beatty, 62-67. A Festschrift for Richard C. Lewontin. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, 2001. 

[3] Bourdieu, P. “Le capital social: notes provisoires.” Actes de la Recherches en Sciences Sociales 3 (1980): 2-3. 

[4] Darnton, R. “President’s Column: History Lessons.” Perspectives on History 37(6) (1999): 1-3. 

[5] Epstein, J. M., and R. Axtell. Growing Artificial Societies: Social Science from the Bottom Up. Washington D C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1996. 

[6] Fogel, R. W., and G. R. Elton. Which Road to the Past? Two Views of History. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983. 

[7] Fogel, R. W. “Economic Growth, Population Theory, and Physiology: The Bearing of Long-Term Processes on the Making of Economic Policy.” American Economic Review 84 (1994): 369-395. 

[8] Goldstone, J. A. Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1991. 

[9] Hopkins, K. “Christian Number and Its Implications.” Journal of Early Christian Studies 6 (1998): 185-226. 

[10] Hunt, L. “President’s Column: Where Have All the Theories Gone?” Perspectives on History 40(3) (2002): 1-3. 

[11] Ibn Khaldun. The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History. Translated from the Arabic by Franz Rosenthal. New York, Pantheon Books, 1958. 

[12] Kingsland, S. Modeling Nature: Episodes in the History of Population Ecology, 2nd edition. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1995. 

[13] Kiser, E., and M. Hechter. “The Role of General Theory is Comparative-Historical Sociology.” American Journal of Sociology 97 (1991): 1-30. 

[14] Korotayev, A., and D. Khaltourina. Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends in Africa. URSS, Moscow, 2006. 

[15] Kradin, N. N. “Nomads, World-Empires, and Social Evolution.” In Alternative routes to civilization (in Russian), edited by N. N. Kradin, A. V. Korotayev, D. M. Bondarenko, and V. A. Lynshi, 314-336. Logos, Moscow, 2000. 

[16] Lee, J. S. “The Periodic Recurrence of Intrnecine Wars in China.” The China Journal March-April (1931): 111-163. 

[17] McNeill, W. H. The Rise of the West. New York: New American Library, 1963. 

[18] Popper, K. R. The Poverty of Historicism. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1957. 

[19] Putnam, R. D., R. Leonardi, and R. Y. Nanetti. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1993. 

[20] Putnam, R. D. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster, 2000. 

[21] Rashevsky, N. Looking at History through Mathematics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1968. 

[22] Sheehan, J. J. “President’s Column: How Do We Learn from History?” Perspectives on History 43(1) (2005): 1-3. 

[23] Sorokin, P. A. Social and Cultural Dynamics. Vol. III. Fluctuations of Social Relationships, War, and Revolution. New York: American Book Company, 1937. 

[24] Stark, R. The Rise of Christianity: A Sociologist Reconsiders History. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1996. 

[25] Stark, R. “E contrario.” Journal of Early Christian Studies 6 (1998): 259-267. 

[26] Stark, R. The Rise of the Mormonism. New York: Columbia University Press, 2005. 

[27] Stearns, P. N. The Encyclopedia of World History, 6th edition. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin, 2001. 

[28] Taleb, N. N. The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable. New York: Random House, 2007. 

[29] Tilly, C. European Revolutions: 1492-1992. Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1993. 

[30] Toynbee, A. J. A Study of History. London: Oxford University Press, 1956. 

[31] Turchin, P. Historical Dynamics: Why States Rise and Fall. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003a. 

[32] Turchin, P. Complex Population Dynamics: A Theoretical/Empirical Synthesis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003b. 

[33] Turchin, P. War and Peace and War: The Life Cycles of Imperial Nations. New York: Pi Press, 2006a. 

[34] Turchin, P. “Scientific Prediction in Historical Sociology: Ibn Khaldun meets Al Saud.” In History and Mathematics: Historical Dynamics and Development of Complex Societies, edited by P. Turchin, L. Grinin, A. Korotayev, and V. C. de Munck. URSS, Moscow, 2006b. 

[35] Turchin, P., and A. Korotayev. “Population Dynamics and Internal Warfare: A Reconsideration.” Social Science and History 5(2) (2006): 121-158. 

[36] Turchin, P. “Arise ‘cliodynamics’.” Nature 454 (2008): 34-35. 

[37] Turchin, P. 2009a. “Long-Term Population Cycles in Human Societies.” In The Year in Ecology and Conservation Biology, edited by R. S. Ostfeld and W. H. Schlesinger, 1-17. 2009. Ann. N. Y. Acad. Sci. 1162. 

[38] Turchin, P. “A Theory for Formation of Large Empires.” Journal of Global History 4 (2009b): 191-207. 

[39] Turchin, P., and S. Nefedov. Secular Cycles. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009. 

[40] von Haehling, R. “Die Religionszugehörigkeit der hohen Amtsträger des Römischen Reiches seit Constantins I. Alleinherrschaft bis zum Ende der Theodosianischen Dynastie.” Ph.D. dissertation, Bonn, 1978. 

[41] Zhao, W., and S. Z. Xie. Zhongguo ren kou shi: China Population History (in Chinese). Peking: People’s Publisher, 1988.

[42] Carneiro, R. L. 1997. Human History: A Domain of Competing Perspectives. Europaea 3:9-32. 

[43] Bonnell, V. E., and L. Hunt. 1999. Introduction. Pages 1-32 in V. E. Bonnell and L. Hunt, editors. Beyond the Cultural Turn: New Directions in the Study of Society and Culture. University of California Press, Berkeley. 

[44] Williamson, S. H. 1991. “The history of cliometrics.” Research in Economic History, Supplement 6:15-31. 

[45] Hunt, L. 1989. The New Cultural History. University of California Press, Berkeley. 

[46] Sewell, W. H. 2005. Logics of History: Social Theory and Social Transformation. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

BACK TO History, Big History, & Metahistory